Gary Becker






















































Gary Becker

GaryBecker-May24-2008.jpg
Gary Becker speaking in Chicago, May 24, 2008

Born
Gary Stanley Becker


(1930-12-02)December 2, 1930

Pottsville, Pennsylvania, U.S.

Died May 3, 2014(2014-05-03) (aged 83)

Chicago, Illinois, U.S.

Institution
Columbia University
(1957–1968)
University of Chicago
(1968–2014)
Field Social economics
School or
tradition
Chicago School of Economics
Alma mater
Princeton University
University of Chicago
Doctoral
advisor
H. Gregg Lewis
Doctoral
students

David O. Meltzer
Russ Roberts
Shoshana Grossbard
Influences
Milton Friedman
Theodore Schultz
Contributions Analysis of human capital
Rotten kid theorem
Awards
John Bates Clark Medal (1967)
Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1992)
Pontifical Academy of Sciences (1997)
National Medal of Science (2000)
John von Neumann Award (2004)
Presidential Medal of Freedom (2007)

Information at IDEAS / RePEc


Gary Stanley Becker (/ˈbɛkər/; December 2, 1930 – May 3, 2014)[1] was an American economist and empiricist. He was a professor of economics and sociology at the University of Chicago. Described as "the most important social scientist in the past 50 years" by The New York Times,[2] Becker was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1992 and received the United States Presidential Medal of Freedom in 2007.[3] A 2011 survey of economics professors named Becker their favorite living economist over the age of 60, followed by Ken Arrow and Robert Solow.[4]


Becker was one of the first economists to branch into what were traditionally considered topics that belonged to sociology, including racial discrimination, crime, family organization, and drug addiction (see rational addiction). He was known for arguing that many different types of human behavior can be seen as rational and utility maximizing. His approach included altruistic behavior of human behavior by defining individuals' utility appropriately. He was also among the foremost exponents of the study of human capital. Becker was also credited with the "rotten kid theorem."




Contents






  • 1 Biography


  • 2 Nobel Memorial Prize


  • 3 Discrimination


  • 4 Politics


  • 5 Crime and punishment


  • 6 Human capital


  • 7 Families


  • 8 Organ markets


  • 9 Selected publications


  • 10 See also


  • 11 References


  • 12 External links





Biography


Born to a Jewish family[5] in Pottsville, Pennsylvania, Becker earned a B.A. at Princeton University in 1951, and a Ph.D. at the University of Chicago in 1955 with a thesis entitled The Economics of Racial Discrimination.[6] At Chicago, Becker was influenced by Milton Friedman, whom Becker called "by far the greatest living teacher I have ever had".[7] Before turning 30, he began to teach at Columbia University in 1957, and in 1970 returned to the University of Chicago. In 1965 he was elected as a Fellow of the American Statistical Association.[8] Becker was a founding partner of TGG Group, a business and philanthropy consulting company. Becker won the John Bates Clark Medal in 1967. He was elected a Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 1972,[9] and was a member (and for a time the President) of the Mont Pelerin Society.[10] Becker also received the National Medal of Science in 2000.[11]


A political conservative,[12] he wrote a monthly column for Business Week from 1985 to 2004, alternating with liberal Princeton economist Alan Blinder. In 1996 Becker was a senior adviser to Republican Presidential Candidate Robert Dole.[13] In December 2004, Becker started a joint weblog with Judge Richard Posner entitled The Becker-Posner Blog."The Becker-Posner Blog". uchicagolaw. University of Chicago Law School..mw-parser-output cite.citation{font-style:inherit}.mw-parser-output .citation q{quotes:"""""""'""'"}.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-free a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/6/65/Lock-green.svg/9px-Lock-green.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-limited a,.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-registration a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/d/d6/Lock-gray-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-gray-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .citation .cs1-lock-subscription a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/a/aa/Lock-red-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-red-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration{color:#555}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription span,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration span{border-bottom:1px dotted;cursor:help}.mw-parser-output .cs1-ws-icon a{background:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/4/4c/Wikisource-logo.svg/12px-Wikisource-logo.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center}.mw-parser-output code.cs1-code{color:inherit;background:inherit;border:inherit;padding:inherit}.mw-parser-output .cs1-hidden-error{display:none;font-size:100%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-visible-error{font-size:100%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-maint{display:none;color:#33aa33;margin-left:0.3em}.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration,.mw-parser-output .cs1-format{font-size:95%}.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-left,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-left{padding-left:0.2em}.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-right,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-right{padding-right:0.2em}


Becker's first wife was Doria Slote, from 1954 until her death in 1970.[14][13] The marriage produced two daughters, Catherine Becker and Judy Becker.[13] About ten years later, in 1980[14] Becker married Guity Nashat, a historian of the Middle East whose research interests overlapped his own.[15] Becker had two stepsons, Cyrus Claffey and Michael Claffey, from his second marriage.[14][13]


Becker died in Chicago, Illinois, aged 83, on May 3, 2014,[16][17] after complications from surgery at Northwestern Memorial Hospital.[18]


In 2014 he was honored in a three-day conference organized at the University of Chicago.[19]



Nobel Memorial Prize


Becker received the Nobel Prize in 1992 "for having extended the domain of microeconomic analysis to a wide range of human behavior and interaction, including nonmarket behavior".[20]



Discrimination


Becker wrote his dissertation in 1955 at the University of Chicago, which examined the economics of discrimination. At the time, economics was strictly the study of market behavior and market economies. Becker challenged the past era of economics by bringing a new investigation of social matters to economics. Becker's contribution to discrimination was unpopular with people arguing that his theory was not economics. He used the international trade model for his analysis on The Economics of Discrimination. In 1957, the publication of his thesis was the study of social issues and the market. He believed both groups can potentially be harmed. The discriminating firm can limit its own productivity and profitability.


Becker often included a variable of taste for discrimination in explaining behavior. He believes that people often mentally increase the cost of a transaction if it is with a minority against which they discriminate. His theory held that competition decreases discrimination.[21] If firms were able to specialize in employing mainly minorities and offer a better product or service, such a firm could bypass discrepancy in wages between equally productive blacks and whites or equally productive females and males. His research found that when minorities are a very small percentage the cost of discrimination mainly falls on the minorities. However, when minorities represent a larger percentage of society, the cost of discrimination falls on both the minorities and the majority. He also pioneered research on the impact of self-fulfilling prophecies of teachers and employers on minorities. Such attitudes often lead to less investment in productive skills and education of minorities.[citation needed]


Becker recognized that people (employers, customers, and employees) sometimes do not want to work with minorities because they have preference against the disadvantaged groups. He goes on to say that discrimination increases the cost of the firm because in discriminating against certain workers, the employer would have to pay more so that work can proceed without them. If the employer employs the minority, low wages can be provided, but more people can be employed, and productivity can be increased.[22]



Politics



Becker is also famous for his economic analysis of democracy. He asked what determines the extent to which one interest group can exploit another. He considered this exploitation to be deadweight loss, meaning a failure to reach efficiency. As Palda (2013) explains


According to Becker, political equilibrium exists even in non-democratic societies. It arises out of a simple calculation that predatory interest groups and their taxpaying victims make: what return on my investment can I get by lobbying government? Becker's insight is that the gains to predators are linear, but the losses to prey are exponential, thereby stiffening the resistance of victims as the aggression of predators plods on without similarly increased vigor. Think of a gang of robbers taking half the crop from peasants. They then return for the second half. The gain to the gang of the second half cut is the same as in their first extortion. Yet for peasants to lose the last half of their crops means possible starvation and the certain loss of seed corn. They can be expected to resist violently, as they did in the Hollywood movie The Magnificent Seven and in the Japanese movie on which it was based, The Seven Samurai.[23]


Becker's insight was to recognize that deadweight losses put a brake on predation. He took the well-known insight that deadweight losses are proportional to the square of the tax, and used it to argue that a linear increase in takings by a predatory interest group will provoke a non-linear increase in the deadweight losses its victim suffers. These rapidly increasing losses will prod victims to invest equivalent sums in resisting attempts on their wealth. The advance of predators, fueled by linear incentives slows before the stiffening resistance of prey outraged by non-linear damages.[24]


These contributions to politics by Becker have come to be known as "Chicago political economy" of which Becker is considered one of the founding fathers.[25]



Crime and punishment



Jurist Richard Posner has stressed the enormous influence of Becker's work "has turned out to be a fount of economic writing on crime and its control."[26][27]


Becker's interest in criminology arose when he was rushed for time one day. He had to weigh the cost and benefits of legally parking in an inconvenient garage versus in an illegal but convenient spot. After roughly calculating the probability of getting caught and potential punishment, Becker rationally opted for the crime. Becker surmised that other criminals make such rational decisions believing that their judgment is based upon scarce commodity or risk seeking. However, such a premise went against conventional thought that crime was a result of mental illness and social oppression.


While Becker acknowledged that many people operate under a high moral and ethical constraint, criminals rationally see that the benefits of their crime outweigh the cost such as the probability of apprehension, conviction, and punishment, and their current set of opportunities. From the public policy perspective, since the cost of increasing the fine is trivial in comparison to the cost of increasing surveillance, one can conclude that the best policy is to maximize the fine and minimize surveillance. However, this conclusion has limits, not the least of which include ethical considerations.[28]


One of the main differences between this theory and Jeremy Bentham's rational choice theory, which had been abandoned in criminology, is that if Bentham considered it possible to annihilate crime completely (through the panopticon), Becker's theory acknowledged that a society could not eradicate crime beneath a certain level. For example, if 25% of a supermarket's products were stolen, it would be very easy to reduce this rate to 15%, quite easy to reduce it until 5%, difficult to reduce it under 3%, and nearly impossible to reduce it to 0% (a feat that would be so costly to the supermarket that it would outweigh the benefit, if it is even possible).



Human capital


Becker's 1964 book titled Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education has gone through three editions since its original publication. Becker's research was fundamental in arguing for the expansion of human capital. When his research was first introduced it was considered very controversial as some considered it debasing. However, he was able to convince many that individuals make choices of investing in human capital based on rational benefits and cost that include a return on investment as well as a cultural aspect.


His research included the impact of positive and negative habits such as punctuality and alcoholism on human capital. He explored the different rates of return for different people and the resulting macroeconomic implications. He also distinguished between general to specific education and their influence on job-lock and promotions.[29]



Families



Becker has done research on the family, including analyses of marriage, divorce, fertility, and social security. He first analyzed fertility starting in 1960.[30]


In the 1960s he and Jacob Mincer developed the New Home Economics, of which Becker's theory of allocation of time is a centerpiece.[31] Becker argued that such decisions are made in a marginal-cost and marginal-benefit framework and that marriage markets affect allocation into couples and individual well-being. His research examined the impact of higher real wages in increasing the value of time and therefore the cost of home production such as childrearing. As women increase investment in human capital and enter the workforce, the opportunity cost of childcare rises. Additionally, the increased rate of return to education raises the desire to provide children with formal and costly education. Coupled together, the impact is to lower fertility rates. His theory of marriage was published in 1973 and 1974. Among its many insights are that (1) sex ratios (the ratio of men to women in marriage markets) are positively related with wives' relative access to consumption in marriages[32] and (2) men with higher incomes are more likely to be polygamous. He published a paper on divorce in 1977, with his students Robert T. Michael and Elizabeth Landes, hypothesizing that divorces are more likely when there are unexpected changes in income.[33][34] Many of these insights on fertility, marriage, and divorce were included in Becker's A Treatise on the Family, first published in 1981 by Harvard University Press.[35]


In April 2013, in response to the lack of women in top positions in the United States, Becker told Wall Street Journal reporter David Wessel, "A lot of barriers [to women and blacks] have been broken down. That's all for the good. It's much less clear what we see today is the result of such artificial barriers. Going home to take care of the kids when the man doesn't: Is that a waste of a woman's time? There's no evidence that it is." This view was then criticized by economist Charles Jones, who stated, "Productivity could be 9% to 15% higher, potentially, if all [remaining] barriers were eliminated."[36]



Organ markets


A 2007 article by Gary Becker and Julio Elias entitled "Introducing Incentives in the market for Live and Cadaveric Organ Donations"[37] posited that a free market could help solve the problem of a scarcity in organ transplants. Their economic modeling was able to estimate the price tag for human kidneys ($15,000) and human livers ($32,000). It is argued by critics that this particular market would exploit the underprivileged donors from the developing world.[38]



Selected publications




  • Becker, Gary (1993) [1964]. Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education (3rd ed.). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. ISBN 9780226041209.


  • Becker, Gary S. (September 1965). "A theory of the allocation of time". The Economic Journal. 75 (299): 493–517. doi:10.2307/2228949. JSTOR 2228949.



Reprinted as Becker, Gary S. (1995), "A theory of the allocation of time", in Humphries, Jane, Gender and economics, Aldershot, England Brookfield, Vermont, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 113–37, ISBN 9781852788438.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1968), "Discrimination, economic", in Sills, David L., International Encyclopedia of Social Sciences, Vol. 4 Cumu to Elas, New York, New York: Macmillan, pp. 208–10, OCLC 256379373.


Reprinted as Becker, Gary S. (1995), "Discrimination, economic", in Humphries, Jane, Gender and economics, Aldershot, England Brookfield, Vermont, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 385–87, ISBN 9781852788438.



  • Becker, Gary S. (March–April 1968). "Crime and punishment: an economic approach". Journal of Political Economy. 76 (2): 169–217. doi:10.1086/259394. JSTOR 1830482.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1969), "An economic analysis of fertility", in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demographic and economic change in developed countries, a conference of the universities, New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 209–40, ISBN 9780870143021.
    Pdf.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1971). The economics of discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 9780226041049.
    Details.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1971) [1957]. The economics of discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 9780226041155.


  • Becker, Gary S.; Lewis, H. Gregg (March–April 1973). "On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children". Journal of Political Economy, Special Issue: New Economic Approaches to Fertility (part 2). 81 (2): s279–s288. doi:10.1086/260166. JSTOR 1840425.


  • Becker, Gary S. (July–August 1973). "A theory of marriage: part I". Journal of Political Economy. 81 (4): 813–46. doi:10.1086/260084. JSTOR 1831130.
    Pdf.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1974). Essays in the economics of crime and punishment. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research distributed by Columbia University Press. ISBN 9780870142635.


  • Becker, Gary S. (March–April 1974). "A theory of marriage: part II". Journal of Political Economy, Special Issue: Marriage, Family Human Capital, and Fertility (part 2). 82 (2): s11–s26. doi:10.1086/260287. JSTOR 1829987.
    Pdf.


  • Becker, Gary S. (November–December 1974). "A theory of social interactions". Journal of Political Economy. 82 (6): 1063–93. doi:10.1086/260265. JSTOR 1830662.
    Pdf.


  • Becker, Gary S.; Ghez, Gilbert (1975). The allocation of time and goods over the life cycle. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research Distributed by Columbia University Press. ISBN 9780870145148.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1976), "Pride and prejudice", in Becker, Gary S., The economic approach to human behavior, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 15–17, ISBN 9780226041124.
    Chapter preview.


  • Becker, Gary S.; Stigler, George J. (March 1977). "De gustibus non est disputandum". The American Economic Review. 67 (2): 76–90. JSTOR 1807222.


  • Becker, Gary S.; Landes, Elizabeth; Michael, Robert T. (December 1977). "An economic analysis of marital instability". Journal of Political Economy. 85 (6): 1147–87. doi:10.1086/260631. JSTOR 1837421.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1991) [1981]. A treatise on the family. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674906983.
    Details.


  • Becker, Gary S. (August 1983). "A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 98 (3): 371–400. doi:10.2307/1886017. JSTOR 1886017.


  • Becker, Gary S. (January 1985). "Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labor". Journal of Labor Economics, Special Issue: Trends in Women's Work, Education, and Family Building (part 2). 3 (1): s33–s58. doi:10.1086/298075. JSTOR 2534997.



Reprinted as Becker, Gary S. (1995), "Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labor", in Humphries, Jane, Gender and economics, Aldershot, England Brookfield, Vermont, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 153–78, ISBN 9781852788438.



  • Becker, Gary S.; Murphy, Kevin M. (August 1988). "A theory of rational addiction". Journal of Political Economy. 96 (4): 675–700. doi:10.1086/261558. JSTOR 1830469.


  • Becker, Gary S. (December 9, 1992). "Nobel prize lecture: the economic way of looking at life". nobelprize.org. Nobel Media AB.
    Pdf.


  • Becker, Gary S. (1996). Accounting for tastes. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674543560.
    Preview.


  • Becker, Gary S.; Becker, Guity Nashat (1997). The economics of life: from baseball to affirmative action to immigration, how real-world issues affect our everyday life. New York: McGraw-Hill. ISBN 9780070067097.
    Details.


  • Becker, Gary S.; Murphy, Kevin M. (2000). Social economics market behavior in a social environment. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674011212.
    Details.


  • Becker, Gary S.; Elías, Julio Jorge (Summer 2007). "Introducing incentives in the market for live and cadaveric organ donations". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 21 (3): 3–24. doi:10.1257/jep.21.3.3. JSTOR 30033732.
    Pdf.


  • Becker, Gary S. (2012), "When illegals stop crossing the border", in Miniter, Brendan, The 4% solution unleashing the economic growth America needs, New York: Crown Business, ISBN 9780307986153

  • Sandmo, A. (1993). Gary Becker's Contributions to Economics. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 95(1), 7–23. doi:10.2307/3440130



See also



  • Economics imperialism

  • Household production function

  • Social capital

  • List of economists



References





  1. ^ Glaeser, Edward L.; Shleifer, Andrei (2014). "Retrospective: Gary Becker (1930–2014)". Science. 344 (6189): 1233. Bibcode:2014Sci...344.1233G. doi:10.1126/science.1256540. PMID 24926006.


  2. ^ Wolfers, Justin (May 5, 2014). "How Gary Becker Transformed the Social Sciences". New York Times.


  3. ^ "President Bush Announces 2007 Medal of Freedom Recipients". Archived from the original on November 1, 2007. Retrieved 2007-10-30.CS1 maint: BOT: original-url status unknown (link)


  4. ^ https://econjwatch.org/file_download/487/DavisMay2011.pdf


  5. ^ "Gary Becker (1930–2014)". jewishvirtuallibrary.org. Jewish Virtual Library. Retrieved March 29, 2015.


  6. ^ Becker, Gary S. (1971). The economics of discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 9780226041049.
    Details at Google Books



  7. ^ Klein, Daniel B.; Daza, Ryan (September 2013). "Ideological profiles of the economics laureates: Gary S. Becker". Econ Journal Watch. 100 (3): 285–91.
    Pdf.



  8. ^ View/Search Fellows of the ASA, accessed 2016-08-20.


  9. ^ "Book of Members, 1780–2010: Chapter B" (PDF). American Academy of Arts and Sciences. Retrieved May 29, 2011.


  10. ^ "Mont Pelerin Society Directory" (PDF). DeSmogBlog. Retrieved January 28, 2014.


  11. ^ "Home page". uchicago.edu. University of Chicago. Archived from the original on April 16, 2014. Retrieved May 4, 2014.


  12. ^ Teles, Steven M. (2008), "Out of the wilderness", in Teles, Steven M., The rise of the conservative legal movement: the battle for control of the law, Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, p. 98, ISBN 9781400829699.
    Preview.



  13. ^ abcd Hershey Jr., Robert D. (May 4, 2014). "Gary S. Becker, 83, Nobel Winner Who Applied Economics to Everyday Life, Dies". The New York Times. The New York Times Company. Retrieved March 19, 2017.


  14. ^ abc Becker, Gary S. (May 3, 2014). "Gary S. Becker - Biographical". nobelprize.org. Nobel Media AB. Retrieved June 6, 2014.


  15. ^ "Gary S. Becker profile". uchicago.edu. University of Chicago. Archived from the original on October 13, 2014. Retrieved May 4, 2014.


  16. ^ Harms, William (May 4, 2014). "Gary S. Becker, Nobel-winning scholar of economics and sociology, 1930–2014". uchicago.edu. University of Chicago. Retrieved May 4, 2014.


  17. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (May 4, 2014). "Very sad news (blog)". gregmankiw.blogspot.co.uk. Retrieved May 4, 2014.


  18. ^ Baer, Stephanie K. (May 4, 2014). "Nobel-prize winning economist Gary Becker dead at 83". Chicago Tribune. Tribune Publishing. Retrieved June 6, 2014.


  19. ^ Comment, F. P. (4 November 2014). "A school in decline: In Chicago, economists honour Gary Becker - Financial Post".


  20. ^ Staff writer (June 6, 2006). "Gary S. Becker – Facts". nobelprize.org. Nobel Media AB.


  21. ^ OpenLearn. Economics explains discrimination in the labour market (PDF). Open University. Retrieved June 29, 2012.


  22. ^ OpenLearn. "Economics explains discrimination in the labour market". open.edu. Open University. Archived from the original on October 7, 2013.


  23. ^ Palda, Filip (2013). The apprentice economist: seven steps to mastery. Kingston, Ontario, Canada: Cooper-Wolfling. ISBN 9780987788047.


  24. ^ Becker, Gary S. (August 1983). "A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 98 (3): 371–400. doi:10.2307/1886017. JSTOR 1886017.


  25. ^ Palda, Filip. A Better Kind of Violence, Chicago Political Economy, Public Choice, and the Quest for an Ultimate Theory of Power. Cooper-Wolfling Press. 2016.


  26. ^ Posner, Richard A. (2004), "The law and economics movement: from Bentham to Becker", in Posner, Richard A., Frontiers of legal theory, Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, p. 52, ISBN 9780674013605.
    Preview.



  27. ^ Harcourt has also stressed Becker's wide influence on analysis of crime and punishment.

    • Harcourt, Bernard E. (2011), "The Chicago school", in Harcourt, Bernard E., The illusion of free markets: punishment and the myth of natural order, Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, pp. 133–34, ISBN 9780674057265.
      Preview.



  28. ^ Becker, Gary S. (1974), "Crime and punishment: an economic approach", in Becker, Gary S., Essays in the economics of crime and punishment, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research distributed by Columbia University Press, pp. 1–54, ISBN 9780870142635.


  29. ^ Becker, Gary S. (1962). "Investment in Human Capital – a theoretical analysis". The Journal of Political Economy. 70 (5): 9–49. doi:10.1086/258724. JSTOR 1829103.


  30. ^ Becker, Gary S. (1960), "An economic analysis of fertility", in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demographic and economic change in developed countries, a conference of the universities, New York: Columbia University Press, OCLC 176157.


  31. ^ Becker, Gary S. (September 1965). "A theory of the allocation of time". The Economic Journal. 75 (299): 493–517. doi:10.2307/2228949. JSTOR 2228949.

    Reprinted as Becker, Gary S. (1995), "A theory of the allocation of time", in Humphries, Jane, Gender and economics, Aldershot, England Brookfield, Vermont, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 113–37, ISBN 9781852788438.



  32. ^ Becker, Gary S. (July–August 1973). "A theory of marriage: part I". Journal of Political Economy. 81 (4): 813–46. doi:10.1086/260084. JSTOR 1831130.
    Pdf.



  33. ^ Becker, Gary S.; Landes, Elizabeth; Michael, Robert T. (December 1977). "An economic analysis of marital instability". Journal of Political Economy. 85 (6): 1147–87. doi:10.1086/260631. JSTOR 1837421.


  34. ^ Grossbard, Shoshana (2010). "How "Chicagoan" are Gary Becker's Economic Models of Marriage?" (PDF). Journal of the History of Economic Thought. 32 (3): 377–95. doi:10.1017/S1053837210000325. hdl:10419/30471.


  35. ^ Becker, Gary S. (1991) [1981]. A treatise on the family. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674906983.
    Details.



  36. ^ Wessel, David (April 3, 2013). "The economics of leaning in". The Wall Street Journal. News Corp. Retrieved April 4, 2013.


  37. ^ Becker, Gary S.; Elías, Julio Jorge (Summer 2007). "Introducing incentives in the market for live and cadaveric organ donations". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 21 (3): 3–24. doi:10.1257/jep.21.3.3. JSTOR 30033732.
    Pdf.



  38. ^ Jha, Vivekanand; Chugh, Kirpal S. (September 2006). "The case against a regulated system of living kidney sales". Nature Clinical Practice Nephrology. 2 (9): 466–67. doi:10.1038/ncpneph0268. PMID 16941033.




External links






Media related to Gary Becker at Wikimedia Commons




  • Becker-Posner Blog, uchicagolaw.typepad.com; accessed May 4, 2014

  • Ideological profile from Econ Journal Watch


  • Conversations with History: Interview with Gary Becker on YouTube by Harry Kreisler


  • Lecture Series on Human Capital on YouTube (~25 hours)


  • Profile in the Financial Times, June 2006; accessed May 4, 2014

  • Interview with Gary Becker


  • The Becker Center on Chicago Price Theory, pricetheory.uchicago.edu; accessed May 4, 2014


  • Appearances on C-SPAN


  • Roberts, Russ (July 10, 2006). "An Interview with Gary Becker". EconTalk. Library of Economics and Liberty.


  • Gary Becker's opinion/editorials/comments for Project Syndicate, project-syndicate.org; accessed May 4, 2014


  • Selected Bibliography for Gary S. Becker, University of Chicago Library; accessed May 4, 2014


  • Becker, Gary S. (2008). "Human Capital". In David R. Henderson. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2nd ed.). Indianapolis, IN: Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0865976658. OCLC 237794267.


  • Gary Stanley Becker (1930–2014). The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty (2nd ed.). Liberty Fund. 2008.


  • Gary Becker publications indexed by Google Scholar









Awards
Preceded by
Ronald H. Coase

Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
1992
Succeeded by
Robert W. Fogel
Douglass C. North















Popular posts from this blog

Italian cuisine

Bulgarian cuisine

Carrot